Match!

A target-based foundation for the "hard-easy effect" bias

Published on Oct 1, 2014
· DOI :10.1007/978-3-319-46319-3_41
Robert F. Bordley4
Estimated H-index: 4
(UM: University of Michigan),
Marco LiCalzi14
Estimated H-index: 14
(Ca' Foscari University of Venice),
Luisa Tibiletti9
Estimated H-index: 9
(UNITO: University of Turin)
Sources
Abstract
The “hard-easy effect” is a well-known cognitive bias on self-confidence calibration that refers to a tendency to overestimate the probability of success in hard-perceived tasks, and to underestimate it in easy-perceived tasks. This paper provides a target-based foundation for this effect, and predicts its occurrence in the expected utility framework when utility functions are S-shaped and asymmetrically tailed. First, we introduce a definition of hard-perceived and easy-perceived task based on the mismatch between an uncertain target to meet and a suitably symmetric reference point. Second, switching from a target-based language to a utility-based language, we show how this maps to equivalence between the hard-perceived target/gain seeking and the easy-perceived target/loss aversion. Third, we characterize the agent’s miscalibration in self-confidence. Sufficient conditions for acting according to the “hard-easy effect” and the “reversed hard-easy effect” biases are set out. Finally, we derive sufficient conditions for the “hard-easy effect” and the “reversed hard-easy effect” to hold. As a by-product we identify situations in enterprise risk management where misconfidence in judgments emerges. Recognizing these cognitive biases, and being mindful of to be normatively influenced by them, gives the managers a better framework for decision making.
  • References (32)
  • Citations (2)
📖 Papers frequently viewed together
2017
3 Citations
7 Citations
2016
10 Citations
78% of Scinapse members use related papers. After signing in, all features are FREE.
References32
Newest
#1Jong Seok Lee (U of M: University of Memphis)H-Index: 18
#2Mark Keil (GSU: Georgia State University)H-Index: 54
Last. Kin Fai Ellick Wong (HKUST: Hong Kong University of Science and Technology)H-Index: 22
view all 3 authors...
Escalation of commitment to a failing course of action is a problem in behavioral decision making that occurs across a wide range of social contexts. In this research, we show that examining escalation of commitment from a goal setting theory perspective provides fresh insights into how goal difficulty influences escalation of commitment. Specifically, through a series of two experiments, we found a curvilinear relationship between goal difficulty and post-feedback goal commitment, which was med...
11 CitationsSource
#1Simona Sacchi (University of Milan)H-Index: 12
#2Luca Stanca (University of Milan)H-Index: 17
Recent studies show that, while losses loom larger than equivalent non-gains, gains loom larger than equivalent non-losses. This finding, at odds with the loss aversion principle, has been interpreted within the framework of regulatory focus theory. In this study, we explore the causal effect of regulatory focus on the asymmetric perception of gains vs non-losses and losses vs non-gains. We examine the perceived effects of both hypothetical and actual changes in monetary wealth, while orthogonal...
6 CitationsSource
In an enterprise risk management environment, managers regularly can expect to be called upon to assess the probability that they will meet financial commitments. The ability to do so makes planning easier and enables the prudent risk taking that is crucial to driving growth. But even highly experienced managers are prone to overconfidence—one of the well-known behavioral biases that can negatively affect their ability to form an accurate assessment. Estimating probability is, in fact, no simple...
2 CitationsSource
#1Michael M. Roy (NWU: North-West University)H-Index: 11
#2Michael J. Liersch (NYU: New York University)H-Index: 7
Last. Stepehen Broomell (CMU: Carnegie Mellon University)H-Index: 1
view all 3 authors...
People have been shown to view their beliefs as being prototypical (modal) but their abilities as (falsely) unique (above or below average). It is possible that these two viewpoints – self as prototypical and self as unique – can be reconciled. If the distribution of ability for a given skill is skewed such that many others have high (low) ability and few others have low (high) ability, it is possible that a majority of peoples’ self-assessments can be above (below) average. Participants in 5 st...
8 CitationsSource
#1Stephen V. Burks (UMN: University of Minnesota)H-Index: 18
#2Jeffrey P. Carpenter (Middlebury College)H-Index: 35
Last. Aldo Rustichini (UMN: University of Minnesota)H-Index: 50
view all 4 authors...
Evidence from both psychology and economics indicates that individuals give statements that appear to overestimate their ability compared to that of others. We test three theories that predict such relative overconfidence. The first theory argues that overconfidence can be generated by Bayesian updating from a common prior and truthful statements if individuals do not know their true type. The second theory suggests that self-image concerns asymmetrically affect the choice to receive new informa...
49 CitationsSource
#1Arvid O. I. Hoffmann (UM: Maastricht University)H-Index: 13
#2Sam F. Henry (UM: Maastricht University)H-Index: 1
Last. Nikos Kalogeras (UM: Maastricht University)H-Index: 13
view all 3 authors...
This paper examines the importance of aspirations as reference points in a multi-period decision-making context. After stating their personal aspiration level, 172 individuals made six sequential decisions among risky prospects as part of a choice experiment. The results show that individuals make different risky-choices in a multi-period compared to a single-period setting. In particular, individuals’ aspiration level is their main reference point during the early stages of decision-making, whi...
23 CitationsSource
#1Sandra Ludwig (LMU: Ludwig Maximilian University of Munich)H-Index: 5
#2Philipp C. Wichardt (University of Bonn)H-Index: 9
Last. Hanke WickhorstH-Index: 2
view all 3 authors...
In this paper, we show that moderate overconfidence in a contest can improve the agent's performance relative to an unbiased opponent and even lead to an advantage in absolute terms.
9 CitationsSource
#1A. Peter McGraw (CU: University of Colorado Boulder)H-Index: 22
#2Jeff T. Larsen (TTU: Texas Tech University)H-Index: 27
Last. David A. Schkade (UCSD: University of California, San Diego)H-Index: 43
view all 4 authors...
Loss aversion in choice is commonly assumed to arise from the anticipation that losses have a greater effect on feelings than gains, but evidence for this assumption in research on judged feelings is mixed. We argue that loss aversion is present in judged feelings when people compare gains and losses and assess them on a common scale. But many situations in which people judge and express their feelings lack these features. When judging their feelings about an outcome, people naturally consider a...
99 CitationsSource
#1R. Preston (California Institute of Technology)H-Index: 37
#2Hugo M. Mialon (Emory University)H-Index: 10
Last. Sue H. Mialon (Emory University)H-Index: 7
view all 3 authors...
"That sunk costs are not relevant to rational decision making is often presented as one of the basic principles of economics. When people are influenced by sunk costs in their decision making, they are said to be committing the "sunk cost fallacy." Contrary to conventional wisdom, we argue that in a broad range of situations, it is rational for people to condition behavior on sunk costs because of informational content, reputational concerns, or financial and time constraints. Once all the eleme...
46 CitationsSource
#1B. Abdous (Université du Québec à Trois-Rivières)H-Index: 1
#2Radu Theodorescu (Laval University)H-Index: 9
, 1983). To the best of our knowledge, the discrete case has not been yetinvestigated. In this note, we give a su†cient condition under which the mean-median-mode inequality holds for a discrete random variable.Let X be a random variable and denote by F its distribution function. If X isZ-valued, denote by fp
20 CitationsSource
Cited By2
Newest
#1Kirsten Wüst (Pforzheim University of Applied Sciences)H-Index: 7
#2Hanno Beck (Pforzheim University of Applied Sciences)H-Index: 5
Source
#1Kai BarronH-Index: 1
#2Christina GravertH-Index: 5
Confidence is often seen as the key to success. Empirical evidence about how such beliefs about one\'s abilities causally map into actions is, however, sparse. In this paper, we experimentally investigate the causal effect of an increase in confidence about one\'s own ability on two central choices made by workers in the labor market: choosing between jobs with different incentive schemes, and the subsequent choice of how much effort to exert within the job. An exogenous increase in confidence l...
1 Citations